Consumer Research Implications of Random Coefficient Models
ABSTRACT - Random coefficient models, in general, and the Hedonic Demand Model (HDM) in particular, are reviewed to show their basic properties and relevance to consumer research. Links to the three traditional tools of multi-attribute models, individual differences scaling, and market segmentation are established. An empirical application of the HDM to auto demand is described. The conclusion integrates the review of the HDM and random coefficient models, generally, with consumer research objectives and requirements.
Citation:
N. Scott Cardell, Ricardo Dobson, and Frederick C. Dunbar (1978) ,"Consumer Research Implications of Random Coefficient Models", in NA - Advances in Consumer Research Volume 05, eds. Kent Hunt, Ann Abor, MI : Association for Consumer Research, Pages: 448-455.
Random coefficient models, in general, and the Hedonic Demand Model (HDM) in particular, are reviewed to show their basic properties and relevance to consumer research. Links to the three traditional tools of multi-attribute models, individual differences scaling, and market segmentation are established. An empirical application of the HDM to auto demand is described. The conclusion integrates the review of the HDM and random coefficient models, generally, with consumer research objectives and requirements. INTRODUCTION Recent econometric modeling developments using random coefficients for probability choice behavior can be linked to prior consumer research on multiattribute models, individual differences scaling, and market segmentation. An experimental econometric technique estimates a hedonic demand model which incorporates selected elements from each of the other three standard analytical procedures from market research. Therefore, the new econometric modeling developments can be readily inserted into the array of consumer research analysis tools by reviewing the standard methodological procedures to show their relationship to the hedonic demand model. Consumer research procedures, such as multiattribute models, are often connected with psychological assumptions of one kind or another. For example, Fishbein (1967) speculated that attitudes toward an object are a function of beliefs about the attributes of that object and the value of those attributes to a consumer. Several variations of his basic assumption have been proposed by Lehmann (1971), Hansen (1969) and others, and empirical research evaluates the nature of the relationships between attitudes toward an object, beliefs about the attributes of a product, and the importance or value of those attributes to consumers (Sheth and Tuncalp, 1975; Sheth, 1973). Individual differences scaling is another consumer research tool which relies heavily on psychological principles. In this case, the early work on nonmetric multidimensional scaling (Shepard, 1962a, 1962b; Kruskal, 1964a, 1964b) was followed into its extension so that each individual could be represented with a separate multidimensional space (Carroll, 1972; Carroll and Chang, 1970; Cliff, 1968; Tucker and Messick, 1963). Applications of individual differences scaling within consumer research are multitudinous (e.g., Green and Rao, 1972; Dobson and Nicolaidis, 1976; Benjamin, 1977). Market segmentation builds on sociological concepts which respect the importance of groups of consumers relative to individual consumers. A fundamental tenet of market segmentation is that people have different preferences for products and services, but no individual, at least not a representative one, is totally distinct. Numerous empirical applications of market segmentation have been reported (Bass, Tigert, and Lonsdale, 1968; Blattberg and Sen, 1974; Haley, 1968; Johnson, 1971). The hedonic demand model (HDM) falls in the tradition of econometric random coefficient models. It is related to multiattribute research because it presumes that the utility of a product is based on one or more of its attributes. Since different individuals are allowed to differentially weight these attributes in the assessment of a product's utility, HDM shares features with individual differences scaling. Furthermore, the model is designed to work with aggregate databases, such as those which report only market shares, and therefore the orientation of HDM is compatible with market segmentation. This presentation has three principal sections. Initially, a theoretical overview of random coefficient models is provided. The second section builds on the overview to establish a bridge between HDM and standard consumer research tools. This conceptual bridge should facilitate the adoption of HDM in consumer research. Finally, the third section describes some empirical results derived by applying the modeling orientation to the demand for autos. THEORETICAL OVERVIEW Random coefficient models can be characterized by their concern with the aggregate behavior of consumers although assumptions about individual differences are inherent to them. The models concentrate on how many consumers would buy a good rather than on which consumers would buy it. Traditionally, such models have been intrinsically linear and this limited their application to a wide class of consumer products. More recently, random coefficient models have been applied to the problem of consumers choosing only one among a finite number of items. This modeling orientation builds on economic antecedents which represent the utility of goods and services in terms of a bundle of attributes (Court, 1941; Lancaster, 1966). Empirical implications of this modeling orientation have been explored in various empirical studies (see, for example, Griliches, 1972; Charles River Associates, 1977; Hausman and Wise, 1976). The Linear Demand Model The value of the random coefficient approach can be shown by considering its application to linear equations. The demand relationships in linear form can be written as follows: Di = SkSj bkj hkj + ei (1) where: Di = the amount of the ith good to be consumed in aggregate, hkj = the kth attribute of the jth good including its price, b
e
i = independently distributed stochastic error term with mean zero and constant variance.The above relationship, modified with demographic variables, is the workhorse of econometric demand studies with aggregate data.
There are several drawbacks to Equation (1). The first is that the coefficients will vary among individuals, thereby leading to biased estimates of the
bkj's if they are assumed to be constant across the population (Theil, 1971). If a product's prices or attributes are changed, then the model will misforecast the change in demand.To cope with this problem models have been developed which allow the
bkj's to vary across individuals (Zellner, 1966; Swamy, 1974). It may be presumed, for example, that tastes for product attributes are distributed normally. If each bkj is stochastically independent and if the hkj's are nonstochastic with finite variance and independent of the bkj's, then the mean and variance of the bkj's can be estimated with generally available regression methods. Theil (1971) points out that these restrictions are not necessarily innocuous. However, the model is appropriate to a large number of situations where consumer behavior needs to be inferred from aggregate data.Probability Choice
Suppose that a product is such that consumers have a finite set of options and buy one such item on occasion to the exclusion of others. For example, a household may consider several different makes of autos, but it will usually purchase only one at a time. The time between purchases is usually substantial (e.g., more than a year). Other durable goods, such as refrigerators and televisions, are acquired in a similar fashion.
Now consider the problem of estimating the shares of various brands or models of such a product. It is well known that the linear specification given in Equation (1) misspecifies consumer behavior even if disaggregate data are used (Domencich and McFadden, 1975; Charles River Associates, 1973).
A class of models used to analyze consumer behavior under these conditions is based on the tenets of probability choice (Luce, 1959). They are widely used by transportation researchers (see Stopher and Meyburg, 1976, for a historical development of probability choice models in transportation). The most typical application is the use of the binary or multinomial logit model to estimate the probability of a traveler selecting one of several transport modes to make a trip. From a consumer research perspective, this decision can be generalized to the selection of one product or service over another. The probability of a consumer choosing alternative i (Pi) from n elements can be expressed as:
where:
hkj = the attributes (which are denoted by k) of each of the n alternatives, and
b
kj = weights assigned to the attributes.Equation (2) is a multinomial logit model, and it de- scribes the probability of choice for alternative i as an S-shaped function of each of the product or service attributes. The sum of the Pi over individuals or households yields the demand, Di, for the product.
Individual differences are not built into the underlying assumptions of the multinomial logit model. Sociodemographic descriptions of consumers can be inserted into Equation (2) to account for individual differences in alternative selection for cases in which the attributes of alternatives are invariant.
The probability choice framework is an advance but the assumption of constant coefficients is very limiting. To see this, suppose everyone in the population can choose among the same set of products. In a cross section of data, this means that the hkj are constant for everyone. Thus, they have no explanatory power for observed differences in choices among products. Even if we have a time series of aggregate observations where changes in product shares can be correlated with changes in product attributes, we cannot estimate the
bkj's in Equation (2) using standard statistical techniques (see McFadden, 1974b) .Even with the important theoretical advance of probability choice models, the problem of predicting product acceptance cannot be easily solved using aggregate data and assuming constant coefficients in the attributes of products. There are other options such as using special surveys or experiments, both of which may be costly. Alternatively, one can drop the assumption of constant coefficients and use widely available aggregate data. This option is explored below.
The Hedonic Demand Model
The hedonic demand model (HDM) allows using aggregate data to estimate market shares among very similar products. It is based on the theory of probability choice behavior while taking account of differences in individuals' tastes. The following develops the behavioral foundations of the model.
A basic assumption is that consumers select that alternative which yields the greatest utility. The utility (denoted by U) derived by a consumer (denoted by x) confronted with several discrete goods, Di, and all other goods and services, Z, can be represented by:
U (Di, Z|x) (3)
It is useful to require that expenditures on Z and the selected alternative equal a consumer's income, Ix, so that:
Ix = DiPi +
pZ (4)where:
Di = 1 for the selected alternative and 0 for all other alternatives,
Pi = alternative prices, and
p
Z = the price index for all other goods and services.Therefore, the choice situation being modeled can be rep- resented by:
U(Di, Z|x) > U(Di, Z|x) for all Di, i/=j, (5)
and the budget constraint of
Ix = DjPj +
pZ (6)It is also convenient to assume separability between utility based on D and Z so that the link to product attributes can be shown as:
U(hj|x) > U(hj|x) for all i/=j (7)
where:
hj = the vector of attributes of good j, and
x = the vector of taste characteristics.
Since Z does not vary when different Di are evaluated. Equation (7) is equivalent to Equation(5) under the assumption of separability.
A further assumption of separability and additivity among the attributes makes it possible to define
where:
hkj = attributes, such as size, horsepower, and price in the case of an auto, and
xk = the tastes of a consumer with respect to those attributes.
There are m attributes under consideration.
Different consumers are represented by different xk. The distribution of tastes across consumers and over attributes can be characterized by multivariate probability density functions.
It is useful for interpretive purposes to normalize the xk so that the taste coefficient of price for each consumer is -1. This normalization permits Equation (8) to be rewritten as:
where:
xk = marginal utilities which indicate the price a consumer would pay for another unit of the kth attribute.
Even when one product dominates another on all attributes, it might be selected by a small fraction of consumers. In order to simulate this potential occurrence, it is convenient to allow a stochastic error term to be added to the utility function of Equation (9). It is usually assumed that the error term is distributed independently and identically across consumers. With the error term, the utility of alternative j can be represented as:
As a consequence of this error term, the probability of j being selected over i can be denoted by:
Therefore, for the fraction of the cases in which the
ei - ej is greater than the quantity on the left of Equation (12), alternative i will be selected even when it is dominated on all attributes by alternative j.While the
e's are distributed independently according to a scaled Weibull distribution, at the level of individual consumers we have a multinomial logit model. However, the parameters of HDM differ across individuals. It is not appropriate, therefore, to apply the multinomial model directly to aggregate market share data. It is necessary instead to estimate the moments (i.e., the mean, variance, and higher ones if appropriate) of an assumed distribution of taste differences across individuals. As the random coefficient models are normally applied, the distribution of taste differences is not directly observed. The distribution is assumed to follow a suitable density function, such as log normal. The data requirements of HDM are substantially reduced by working with an assumed instead of an observed distribution of taste parameters.McFadden (1974a) has shown that in this case the probability of an individual choosing good j from among n goods given tastes xk is:
Equation (13) can be used to help derive the mean,
m, and the standard deviation, s, of consumer tastes by integrating over xk:where f(xk:
m, S) is the probability density function for the multivariate distribution of consumer tastes over attributes with mean vector D and variance-covariance matrix:The probability expression of Equation (14) involves a rather complex integral -- its order of integration is the same as the number of attributes. While it is impossible to analytically evaluate Equation (14) except under severely simplifying assumptions, numerical integration is possible. Numerical integration relies on Monte Carlo procedures. Pi (
m,s) can be approximated by taking the average of many calculated Pi from Equation (14) where xk is a random vector generated from a multivariate probability density function with mean m and variance-covariance matrix Z. The details of the solution algorithm and the specification of functional forms of xk are discussed at length elsewhere (Charles River Associates, 1977) and they will not be summarized here since they are not essential to the points being made.TIES TO STANDARD CONSUMER RESEARCH TECHNIQUES
Random coefficient models are important for consumer research because of the wide range of topics to which they are relevant and the inherent power of the research strategy. In this section, we describe relationships between standard consumer research techniques and HDM in order to highlight the value of this recent econometric development vis-a-vis the analysis of consumer behavior. In particular, three techniques are compared and contrasted with HDM: multiattribute models; individual differences scaling; and market segmentation.
Multiattribute Models
A common form of the multiattribute model has been described by Wilkie and Pessemier (1973). They write a linear compensatory representation in these symbols:
where
i = attribute or product characteristic,
j = brand, and
k = consumer or respondent;
such that:
"jk = consumer k's attitude score for brand j,
Iik = the importance weight given to attribute i by consumer k, and
Bijk= consumer k's belief as to the extent to which attribute i is offered by brand j.
Consumer researchers have extensively studied variations of this formulation. The original attitude conceptualizations were proposed by Rosenberg (1956) and Fishbein (1967). The relationships among Ajk, Iik, and Bijk have been examined under different measurement conditions and modeling frameworks.
A gap in the theoretical development of early multiattribute formulations was the nature of the relationship between Ajk and consumer behavior. The link between attitude and behavior is implicit with positive attitudes assumed to correlate with positive behavior, but it is known that better predictors of behavior are available.
The strength of the approach is diagnosis as opposed to prediction. Diagnosis results from the exposure of the salience of different product attributes as seen by consumers. To the extent that managers can change product attributes, they can use multiattribute modeling research to help them improve the salience of their product to consumers.
The utility equation (see Equation (10)) of HDM is defined in terms of coefficients for different attributes, in a similar manner to multiattribute models. However, the attributes, hkj, are direct observations on products as opposed to respondents' judgments about product attributes. The utility concept is directly linked to consumer choice through utility maximization and probability representations (see Equations (13) and (14)). Finally, the taste coefficients, xk in Equation (10) generally correspond to Iik, of Equation (16), but they are estimated from aggregate data on market shares instead of being reported by respondents. Therefore, the random coefficient models do not require data from individual respondents. In the latter sense, they are more parsimonious in their data needs; this reduces the cost of analysis and thus adds to the desirability of HDM.
The theoretical basis of HDM is inherently reasonable, and its relationship to consumer behavior is explicit. Consumers are assumed to select the product with the largest utility to them, and utility is defined as a weighted function of attributes and a stochastic term. The weights for attributes are consumer taste coefficients which are estimated to maximize the likelihood of predicting aggregate market share data across respondents.
Individual Differences Scaling
Individual differences scaling follows from psychological research on perceptions and preferences. The notion is that the differences among individuals in preferences or perceptions can be used to quantify the similarities and differences among individuals. With respect to marketing research, it is assumed that these differences have implications with respect to consumer behavior. Among the models which have been commonly used for individual differences scaling are INDSCAL (Carroll and Chang, 1970), the vector model (Tucker, 1960), and variations of the ideal point model (Coombs, 1964).
There are at least four types of applications for individual differences scaling in consumer research. In common with aggregate multidimensional scaling, the technique finds how product attributes vary among one another from the user's perspective. Beyond this point, individual differences scaling is much more flexible. It is possible, for example, to stratify a sample along one or more sociodemographic variables to study how shifts in perceptions and/or preferences vary across strata. It is alternatively possible to cluster consumers according to their perceptions and/or preferences and examine shifts in sociodemographic variables over perceptual market segments. When it is more useful to find homogeneous perceptual segments than study variation along one or more prespecified sociodemographic variables, the latter procedure is to be preferred over the former. Both techniques, however, will reveal interrelationships of particular types of viewpoints with sociodemographic variables. A fourth application involves using an individual's weights or saliences for perceptual dimensions as the independent variables in a multiattribute formulation. The dependent variable is usually some indicator of consumer preference or purchase patterns. Illustrations of the above four applications are described in numerous sources (see for example, Dobson, Golob and Gustafson, 1974; Dobson and Kehoe, 1975; Green and Carmone, 1972; Green and Rao, 1972; and Dobson and Nicolaidis, 1976).
Individual differences scaling and HDM have complementary and contrasting relationships to each other. There are no guidelines within HDM to select attributes, but individual differences scaling can be used to highlight product attributes which are salient to major market segments. Physical indicators of these psychologically salient attributes could then be used in HDM. It is possible to use output from individual differences scaling in a multiple attribute representation which parallels that of HDM, but the interpretations of the two representations are substantially at variance. In the case of individual differences scaling, consumer tastes, as denoted by saliences for perceptual dimensions, are the independent variables. These tastes are then weighted to account for indicators of consumer preferences or purchase patterns. HDM, however, uses consumer tastes as weights instead of independent variables. Further, these consumer tastes are linked to behavior via a nonlinear, probability choice formulation rather than the linear, compensatory formulation frequently used with individual differences scaling output.
Both random coefficient models and individual differences scaling relate to market segmentation. The random coefficient models are attractive, in part because they can be estimated on aggregated market segmentation data. For HDM, the aggregate data are market shares for different products, a type of information which is frequently readily available. On the other hand, individual differences scaling will normally require a special data collection effort, but its output can be used to form market segments based on perceptual characteristics of respondents. For product positioning with respect to consumer segments in a broad, qualitative sense, the richness of individual differences scaling may be more useful, but for detailed, quantitative estimates of market shares, HDM may be more useful. In any event, there are opportunities for meaningful consumer research in comparing and contrasting the alternative methodologies.
Market Segmentation
Market segmentation in consumer research is predicated on two key concepts. It is initially assumed that meaningful groups of users of a product or service can be identified. The second concept revolves around the creative assessment of product and/or service requirements for different market segments. These concepts are jointly applied towards maximizing profits through rendering services and/or products which appeal strongly to lucrative market segments.
A variety of criteria have been proposed for assessing whether any particular group of market segments is appropriate for profit maximization. Kotler (1972) notes that it is important for segments to be measurable, accessible, and substantial. Wilkie and Cohen (1976) remark that "true" segments should be homogeneous within and heterogeneous between groups, useful as a behavioral correlate, and efficient to market from production, distribution, and pricing perspectives. A pivotal aspect of market segmentation is the selection of appropriate variables on which to divide consumers. The term segmentation basis is used to denote a set of variables selected to divide consumers. Three principal classes of bases are sociodemographic data (Carman, 1965; Assael and Roscoe, 1976), consumption patterns (Cunningham, 1955), and individuals' subjective judgments (Haley, 1968; Myers, 1976). A major summary and analysis of segmentation research and theory is provided by Frank, et al. (Frank, Massey and Wind, 1975).
As noted above , HDM is organized around a segmentation structure, namely the market shares for different products. The primary thrust of this modeling orientation is to derive estimates of consumer tastes which are consonant with market share data. This consumer taste information can be used for product planning purposes. Also, market simulations can be performed which reveal the implications of an altered product mix. HDM assumes that the set of salient product attributes are known and that the purpose of a marketing analysis is to study substitution among products. When either of these conditions does not hold, another market segmentation analysis technique may be more appropriate. More traditional consumer research tools for market segmentation are directed at product positioning (i.e., what new product would consumers most like to have) and advertising targeting (i.e., what content should a promotional campaign have and to whom should it be addressed). A potentially useful purpose of the traditional approaches is the evaluation of marketing strategy effectiveness (Assael and Roscoe, 1976). It can be seen, therefore, that traditional consumer techniques and HDM complement each other with respect to market segmentation.
AN APPLICATION OF HDM TO AUTOS
The hedonic demand model was developed in a study of the impact of foreign trade controls on the import share of new car sales (Charles River Associates, 1976). The technique yields predictions of the effects of changes in prices and characteristics of any set of automobile models on the market shares of individual models. The predictions of share changes for individual models are then summed to obtain the predicted change in the share of a class of models resulting from any relative price changes.
The input data used are the price, selected attributes, and new car sales in a given time period of a set of automobile models. The attributes include available characteristics which either contribute to, or are correlated with, the quality of a car. Available attributes data for recent years include both the physical dimensions from Automotive News Almanac and performance data collected by the U.S. Department of Transportation and the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. The physical attributes data include number of cylinders, headroom, height, horsepower, legroom, length, gas tank capacity, transmission type (automatic or manual), turning circle weight and width. The performance variables used were acceleration and fuel economy (miles per gallon). The sample period was the five-month period between April 1974 and August 1974; this period was selected to include the part of the 1974 model year subsequent to the period of acute gasoline shortage.
The results presented below should be viewed as first-run estimates only. Still, the results seem quite plausible and are very similar both to estimates from time series regressions and to a set of predictions of the impact of imported car price increases on market shares derived by questionnaire techniques (Market Facts, 1976).
The estimate of the taste distribution for characteristics which was used to derive the share elasticities with respect to relative price changes was based on five attribute variables: volume, passenger area, weight, turning circle, and gallons per mile. Volume is defined as the product of length, width, and height, and is a proxy measure for a combination of total seating capacity and trunk space. Passenger area is computed as the product of headroom and legroom, and represents a proxy for driver and front seat passenger comfort. Utility is positively correlated with volume, passenger area, and weight. Utility is negatively correlated with turning circle diameter (the smaller the turning circle, the more maneuverable the automobile) and with fuel consumption in gallons per mile.
Table 1 summarizes statistical information on the estimated distributions of the marginal rates of substitution between characteristics and price. The distribution of consumer tastes for auto attributes is assumed to be log-normal. The statistics reported in Table 1 were computed by taking exponents of the parameters of the normal distributions of the logs of the attributes. As the distributions are log-normal, the mean and median of the distributions are not the same.
DISTRIBUTION OF ESTIMATED MARGINAL VALUES OF AUTOMOBILE CHARACTERISTICS (DOLLARS PER UNIT)
The numbers reported in Column (2) of Table 1, the median of the distributions, give the marginal value of an additional unit of the attribute in dollars; the units of the characteristics are defined at the bottom of Table 1. The coefficient attached to VOL 2 indicates that the median consumer is willing to pay $2.31 for an extra 10,000 cubic inches of volume. The coefficient attached to weight indicates that the median consumer is willing to pay an additional $2.78 for an additional pound. The median coefficient for turning radius is greater than for VOL 2, AREAG, and WEIGHT, but there is also the most differentiation among consumers on this attribute. Note the extremely large variance of consumer tastes for this attribute in Column (3). The median marginal utility for gallons per mile is the greatest of all the attributes. This coefficient, which was derived from data collected immediately after the oil embargo, shows the extreme sensitivity of consumers to gasoline availability. However, despite the time period for which the model is estimated, there is still substantial variability among consumers on the importance of this attribute.
The upper and lower bounds of the 95 percent confidence interval (see Columns (4) and (5)) indicate the degree of dispersion in tastes for each attribute among consumers. The alternative degrees of variability across attributes reveals the ability of HDM to characterize individual differences among consumers. It should also be kept in mind that the model was estimated on physical attributes data and aggregate market share statistics. In any event, it can be seen that the most widely dispersed values are for the attribute "turning circle." Apparently some consumers place a high value on this attribute for parking and general maneuvering ability, but others have practically no preference for it at all. It is likely that a substantial portion of the variation for gallons per mile reflected different expectations among consumers as to gasoline availability and price. The range of variability for the remaining three attributes is substantially narrower than for TURN and GPM.
Table 2 compares the predicted shares consistent with the utility function estimated in the model with actual market shares of different automobile types. The model was estimated using two different price variables --the one year old price in August 1974 of 1974 models reported in National Market Reports, Inc., Red Book and the estimated new transactions price of 1974 models. The new transactions price variable was corrected by applying "typical" discount factors for different types of cars reported in the annual automobile buying issue of Consumer Reports (April 1974) to list prices reported in the 1974 issue of Automotive News Almanac. The data reported in Table 2 show that the predicted shares from the model conform fairly closely to the actual shares; the model fits the data well. For example, the actual share for all domestics was .86798 and the share estimated by the random coefficient model with adjusted new car prices was .86183. Predicted import shares are slightly higher than actual shares. There is little difference in model estimates across the two price indicators which suggests the model is robust in the face of varying data quality.
COMPARISON OF PREDICTED SHARES TO ACTUAL SHARES BY AUTOMOBILE TYPE, APRIL-AUGUST 1974
SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS
A major purpose of this report was to present a recent econometric development which has potential value as a consumer research tool. The historical antecedents and underlying assumptions were initially described. These assumptions were subsequently compared and contrasted with those of three standard consumer research techniques. Finally, an application of the approach to auto demand was summarized. It is clear that HDM parallels the functions of other consumer research techniques, that it requires little data which can be obtained without survey collection costs and time delays, and that it has the potential to produce accurate results which are subject to rich interpretation.
The logic of HDM is based on a simple assumption of utility maximization at the level of individual consumers. Furthermore, the formulation of this model assumes a multiattribute structure, but it is based on physical product attributes. Individual differences among consumers are represented by taste coefficients for the attributes. These coefficients are estimated in a probability choice framework to be consistent with market share data.
As mentioned above, HDM is multiattribute in structure and therefore has a common link with the Fishbein (1967) and Rosenberg (1956) models. A principal difference between the two approaches is the use of physical attribute data versus subjective judgments in the psychological models. The individual differences scaling models, such as INDSCAL, allow for variations among consumers in a fashion which is similar to HDM. However, neither individual differences scaling nor Fishbein models, as initially proposed, were designed to facilitate the estimation of the probability of consumer choice, but HDM is directed toward this objective. Market share data, a type of market segmentation, provide a basis for the estimation of HDM. In the latter respect, a tie is established to a pervasive consumer research tool.
When the model was estimated on auto market share data, its properties were revealed. It was shown that variability among consumers could be represented. It is important to recall that this variability among consumers is described without a reliance on surveys. Only readily available data, such as market shares for models and physical product attributes, were required. In addition, it was possible to estimate a model representation which accurately fitted the data. This ability to accurately describe variability among consumers while correctly estimating market share data is an attractive property, particularly when it is combined with the minimal data requirements of the random coefficient models.
Further research is justified with random coefficient models on the basis of the results described above. These models can have rational structures which show a relationship between utility and probability choice at the level of the individual consumer. They also have extremely simple data requirements. HDM is compatible with standard consumer research functions. Therefore, its use in marketing studies will achieve normal objectives and concurrently extend the state of the art in consumer research.
REFERENCES
H. Assael and A. M. Roscoe, "Approaches to Market Segmentation Analysis," Journal of Marketing, 40 (1976), 67-76.
F. M. Bass, D. G. Tigert, and R. F. Lonsdale, "Marketing Segmentation: Group Versus Individual Behavior," Journal of Marketing Research, 5 (1968), 264-270.
J. M. Benjamin, The Assessment of User Preferences for New Apartments: An Application of Multidimensional Scaling. (unpublished doctoral dissertation, State University of New York, Buffalo, 1977).
R. C. Blattberg and S. K. Sen, "Market Segmentation Using Models of Multidimensional Purchasing Behavior," Journal of Marketing, 38 (1974), 17-28.
J. M. Carman, Studies in Demand for Household Equipment, Research Program in Marketing, University of California, Berkeley, 1965.
J. Carroll, "Individual Differences in Multidimensional Scaling," in R. N. Shepard, A. K. Romney, and S. B. Nerlove, eds., Multidimensional Scaling I (New York: Seminar Press, 1972).
J. Carroll and J. J. Chang, "An Analysis of Individual Differences in Multidimensional Scaling via an N-way Generalization of 'Eckart-Young' Decomposition," Psychometrika, 35 (1970), 283-319.
Charles River Associates, Analysis of the Demand for Cable Television (Cambridge, Massachusetts, 1973).
Charles River Associates, Impacts of Trade Policies on the U.S. Automobile Industry (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Department of Labor, 1976).
Charles River Associates, Methodology for Predicting the Demand for New Electricity Using Goods (Palo Alto, California: Electric Power Research Institute, 1977).
N. Cliff, "The 'Idealized Individual' Interpretation of Individual Differences in Multidimensional Scaling," Psychometrika, 33 (1968), 225-232.
C. H. Coombs, A Theory of Data (New York: John Wiley and Sons, Inc., 1964).
L. M. Court, Entrepreneurial and Consumer Demand Theories for Commodity Spectron," Econometrica, 1941.
R. Cunningham, "Measurement of Brand Loyalty," Proceedings of the American Marketing Association Conferences, 1955, 39-45.
R. Dobson, T. F. Golob, and R. L. Gustafson, "Multidimensional Scaling of Consumer Preferences for a Public Transportation System: An Application of Two Approaches," Socioeconomic Planning Sciences, 8 (1974), 23-36.
R. Dobson and J. Kehoe, "An Empirical Comparison of the Tucker-Messick and INDSCAL Models: Measuring Viewpoints about Transit Attributes," Socio-Economic Planning Sciences, 9 (1975), 67-81.
R. Dobson and G. C. Nicolaidis, "Preferences for Transit Service for Homogeneous Groups of Individuals," Proceedings, Fifteenth Annual Meeting, Transportation Research Forum, 1976.
T. Domencich and D. McFadden, Urban Travel Demand (Amsterdam: North-Holland Publishing Co., 1975).
M. Fishbein, "A Behavior Theory Approach to the Relations between Beliefs about an Object and the Attitude toward an Object," in M. Fishbein, ed., Readings in Attitude Theory and Measurement (New York: John Wiley and Sons, Inc., 1967).
R. Frank, W. F. Massy, and F. Wind, Market Segmentation (Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice-Hall, Inc., 1975).
P. E. Green, and F. J. Carmone, "Marketing Research Applications of Non-metric Scaling Methods," in A. K. Romney, R. N. Shepard, and S. B. Nerlove, eds., Multidimensional Scaling II (New York: Seminar Press, 1972).
P. E. Green and V. R. Rao, Applied Multidimensional Scaling (New York: Holt, Rinehart, and Winston, Inc., 1972).
Z. Griliches, ed., Price Indexes and Quality Change (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press, 1972).
R. I. Haley, "Benefit Segmentation: A Decision Oriented Research Tool," Journal of Marketing, 37 (1968), 30-35.
F. Hansen, "Consumer Choice Behavior: An Experimental Approach," Journal of Marketing Research, 6 (1969), 436-443.
J. Hausman and D. Wise, "A Conditional Probit Model for Qualitative Choice: Discrete Decisions Recognizing Interdependence and Heterogeneous Preferences," Working Paper, Department of Economics, Harvard University, 1976.
R. M. Johnson, "Market Segmentation: A Strategic Management Tool," Journal of Marketing Research, 8 (1971), 13-18.
P. Kotler, Marketing Management (Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice-Hall, Inc., 1972).
J. B. Kruskal, "Multidimensional Scaling by Optimizing to a Nonmetric Hypothesis," Psychometrika, 39 (1964), 1-27.
J. B. Kruskal, "Nonmetric Multidimensional Scaling: A Numerical Method," Psychometrika, 29 (1964), 115-129.
K. J. Lancaster, "A New Approach to Consumer Theory," Journal of Political Economy, 74 (1966), 132-157.
D. R. Lehmann, "Television Show Preference: Application of a Choice Model," Journal of Marketing Research, 8 (1971), 47-55.
R. Luce, Individual Choice Behavior (New York: John Wiley and Sons, Inc., 1959).
Market Facts, A Foreign Automobile Impact Study (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Department of Labor, 1976).
D. McFadden, "Conditional Logit Analysis of Qualitative Choice Behavior," in Paul Zarembka, ed., Frontiers in Econometrics (New York: Academic Press, 1974a).
D. McFadden, "The Measurement of Urban Travel Demand," Journal of Public Economics (1974b).
J. H. Myers, "Benefit-Structure Analysis: A New Tool for Product Planning," Journal of Marketing, 40 (1976), 23-32.
J. M. Rosenberg, "Cognitive Structure and Attitudinal Affect," Journal of Abnormal and Social Psychology, 53 (1956), 367-372.
R. N. Shepard, "The Analysis of Proximities: Multidimensional Scaling with an Unknown Distance Function. I," Psychometrika, 27 (1962a) 125-140.
R. N. Shepard, "The Analysis of Proximities: Multidimensional Scaling with an Unknown Distance Function. II," Psychometrika, 27 (1962b) 219-246.
J. N. Sheth, "Brand Profiles from Beliefs and Importances,'' Journal of Advertising, 13 (1973), 37-42.
J. N. Sheth, and S. Tuncalp, Structural Assumptions Underlying Fishbein's Expectancy Value Model of Attitudes (Champaign, Illinois: University of Illinois, 1975).
P. R. Stopher and A. H. Meyburg. "Behavioral Travel-Demand Models," in P. Stopher and A. H. Meyburg, eds., Behavioral Travel Demand Models (Lexington, Massachusetts: Lexington Books, 1976).
P. A. V. B. Swamy, "Linear Models with Random Coefficients,'' in P. Zarembka, ed., Frontiers in Econometrics (New York: Academic Press, 1974).
H. Theil, Principles of Econometrics (New York: John Wiley and Sons, Inc., 1971), Chapter 11.
L. R. Tucker, "Intra-individual and Inter-individual Multidimensionality," in H. Gulliksen and S. Messick, eds., Psychological Scaling: Theory and Applications (New York: John Wiley and Sons, Inc., 1960).
L. R. Tucker and S. Messick, "An Individual Difference Model for Multidimensional Scaling," Psychometrika, 28 (1963), 333-367.
W. L. Wilkie, and J. B. Cohen, A Behavioral Science Look at Market Segmentation Research (Gainesville: University of Florida, 1976).
W. L. Wilkie and E. A. Pessemier, "Issues in Marketing's Use of Multi-Attribute Attitude Models," Journal of Marketing Research, 10 (1973), 428-441.
A. Zellner, "On the Aggregation Problem: A New Approach to a Troublesome Problem" Report #6628, Center for Mathematical Studies in Business and Economics, University of Chicago, 1966.
----------------------------------------
Authors
N. Scott Cardell, Charles River Associates, 1050 Massachusetts Avenue, Cambridge, Massachusetts 02138
Ricardo Dobson, Charles River Associates, 1050 Massachusetts Avenue, Cambridge, Massachusetts 02138
Frederick C. Dunbar, Charles River Associates, 1050 Massachusetts Avenue, Cambridge, Massachusetts 02138
Volume
NA - Advances in Consumer Research Volume 05 | 1978
Share Proceeding
Featured papers
See MoreFeatured
Symbolic sustainable attributes improve attitude toward low-quality products: A warm-glow feelings account
Valéry Bezençon, University of Neuchâtel
Florent Girardin, University of Neuchâtel
Renaud Lunardo, Kedge Business School
Featured
The Preference for Simultaneity: When Different Events Happen to Different People at the Same Time
Franklin Shaddy, University of Chicago, USA
Yanping Tu, University of Florida, USA
Ayelet Fishbach, University of Chicago, USA
Featured
How Residential Mobility Influences Donations
Yajin Wang, University of Maryland, USA
Amna Kirmani, University of Maryland, USA
Xiaolin Li, University of Texas at Dallas, USA
Nicole Kim, University of Maryland, USA